Challenging Apartheid’s Foreign Debt
Jeff Rubin
South Africa’s widely commended Truth & Reconciliation Commission has a blind spot. Surprisingly, no
attention appears to have been given to the foreign corporations, individual investors and Western
governments that helped create and sustain the racial dictatorship which came to be known as apartheid.
The Cape Town -based Alternative Information & Development Centre (AIDC) undertook a study and
produced a report on a strategy for challenging the foreign debt incurred during the apartheid era but which
democratic South Africa is now expected to pay. The Report, located in the search for truth and
reconciliation in South Africa, seeks to address the omission of apartheid’s international face. Post-
apartheid So uth Africa has inherited a foreign debt of $18.7 billion (some R90 billion). The dominant view
amongst economists and politicians is that this sum presents no special problem. According to the
measures most economists use in such matters the foreign debt is not a course for concern.
The AIDC’s Report challenges this complacency on three grounds. First, R90 billion is an awful lot of
money for the vast majority of South Africans who, in varying degrees, remain deprived of the basic
necessities of life. Any u nnecessary and unjustifiable diversion of resources away from meeting these
needs has to be opposed and stopped. Second, the balance of payments, which is already near to the
danger zone, might not be able to bear the additional burden of the debt repayments. These repayments, of
between $1.5 billion and $2.6 billion a year for the period 1997 to 2001, are more than enough to create a
balance of payments crisis. Morality and international law provide the third basis for challenging the debt.
Morality and international law lie at the heart of the AIDC’s strategy. The Report revisits the Doctrine of
Odious Debt, a doctrine of jurisprudence the US Government and US Chief justice helped develop. The US
Government, in the aftermath of the American-Spanish War of 100 years ago, used the doctrine to repudiate
Cuba’s debt to Spain. The US Government argued that the debt was “odious” and unenforceable since it
had been incurred without the consent of the Cuban people and by means of force of arms. The US
Government further maintained that the creditors knowingly took the risk of investment when they made the
odious loans.
In 1923, the Royal Bank of Canada sought to recover debt from the recently established democratic
government of Costa Rica. In the Costa Rican submission, the debt was illegitimate. The new government
argued that the debt has been incurred by a dictator not the people of Costa Rica; the submission being
that, at the time the loans were made, the people had been engaged in a political and military struggle to
bring democracy to their country. The case was heard by Chief Justice Taft, of the US Supreme Court. Taft,
sitting as arbitrator, fully upheld the repudiation of the debt.
The legal authority who did most to codify the Doctrine of Odious Debt was the e´migre´ Russian,
Alexander Sack, while he was a Professor of Law in France. It was his opinion that governments invoking
the doctrine would be required to prove that the debt ill-served the public interest and that the creditors
were well aware of this. Provided these proofs were met, the onus would be on the creditors to show that the
funds were utilized for the benefit of the country. If the creditors could not do so before an international
tribunal the debt would be unenforceable.
Using Sack’s principles, the Report argues that all debts incurred during the apartheid years are illegitimate
because the apartheid regime itself was illegitimate. The UN and the International Court of Justice were the
most authoritative of the wide range of international b odies that proclaimed apartheid to be a crime against
humanity.
pg_0002
Apartheid loans came from three sources: the IMF/World Bank, foreign private commercial banks and
individual speculators in various countries around the world. The Report shows how each of these three
groups actively and continuously supported apartheid and worked to undermine the international campaign
to free South Africa from its racial dictatorship.
The Report’s central proposition is that the democratically elected government of the new So uth Africa
should invoke the Doctrine of Odious Debt and should then enter into negotiations with the creditors for
the cancellation of all the foreign debt from the apartheid years.
The Report recognizes, however, that even if sympathetic to the claims of democratic South Africa, the
banks and their governments would probably balk at the precedent it might set for countries with debt
burdens much greater than South Africa’s. The strategy, therefore, anticipates the need for international
solidarity action in support of democratic South Africa and suggests that the people who formed the anti-
apartheid movements around the world would be a natural initial constituency to promote such action.
The Report further calls for the internationalization of both Affirmative Action and South Africa’s
universally praised Truth & Reconciliation program. It invites the outside world — more especially
governmental and business forces in Britain and elsewhere — to acknowledge their own long role in the
creation, development and defense of what eventually came to be known as apartheid. Moreover, many
shareholders, speculators and ordinary citizens in the West benefited, whether directly or indirectly, from
the very features that helped make apartheid a crime against humanity. The injustices inherited from
apartheid that Affirmative Action is supposed to redress thus also have an international dimension.
The Report acknowledges that the debt cancellation might well have a price-tag for a number of Western
citizens, not just large, anonymous and enormously wealthy transnational banks. The document suggest
that the debt cancellation should also be seen as a form of reparation. By canceling the debt, the banks,
governments and peoples of the West would be acknowledging their debt — both financial and moral — to
the oppressed people of South Africa and that this acknowledgment would in effect be the West’s
acknowledgment of its responsibility before the Truth and Reconciliation Commission.
The Report acknowledges that similar arguments can be made for the cancellation of the internal debt that
the beneficiaries of apartheid passed on to democratized South Africa. Tackling the bigger internal debt,
however, requires further research and would be a logical consequence of the settlement of the foreign debt.
The AIDC is currently addressing this aspect of the debt problem.
The Report asks what would happen if South Africa falls in its attempts to negotiate the cancellation of its
foreign debt. In this event, the strategy calls upon the South African Government to be prepared to invoke
the Doctrine of Odious Debt unilaterally. The strategy anticipates that the government will almost certainly
need to be encouraged to take such a unilateral measure. Should South Africa’s negotiators be left with little
option other than unilateral implementation of the Doctrine of Odious Debt, the proposal is for a campaign
by civil society to urge the government to take such a step.
The Report predicts an outraged response from business and some politicians in South Africa to any move
that challenges apartheid’s foreign debt. These sources, it says, will seek to terrify the South African public
with dire warnings of economic collapse. Debt repudiation, according to these predictions, will result in
South Africa alienating such powerful institutions as the World Bank/IMF and “being cut off from
international capital.” To allay these fears — and thereby also to facilitate the mobilization of civil society —
the document brings three certainties to the caution it acknowledges. These certainties are:
the manifest failures of the World Bank/IMF policies elsewhere in the world and particularly in Africa;
the fact that the South African economy survived the unilateral debt freeze that the apartheid
government actually imposed in 1985;
and the clear inability of the Government’s existing macro -economic policy, with its focus on “foreign
investor friendliness” to address the basic needs of the majority of the population.
The document draws attention to three precedents: the Government of the new South Africa unilaterally
canceling the debt owed to South Africa by Namibia and doing so because of the immorality of the debt;
pg_0003
and the Paris Club of western creditor governments canceling a large part of the debt owed by Poland and
Egypt.
The Report ends on a note of urgency. Apartheid’s debt is being paid back now. The strategy to challenge
apartheid’s foreign debt is seriously weakened by time. The need is to act now.
April 1997
Preface
Be Reasonable — Demand the Impossible!
1
The AIDC’s brief is nothing if not audacious: provide a strategy to challenge the foreign debt dumped on
the new South Africa by the apartheid State. The problem of the foreign debt and the need for a counter
strategy is recognized by only a tiny number of small organizations. But it wasn’t always thus. From today’s
vantage point it might be hard to remember that it was once fashionable to be bold and that this practice
went out of fashion only a few years ago. During the late 1980s to early 90s, when the apartheid order was
everywhere crumbling, people were encouraged to be daring. Yet this flowering of radicalism, that covered a
large number of the most creative of the intellectual activists, failed to produce a strategy challenging the
foreign debt. Slogans were not in short supply. Only a coherent and developed plan was missing.2 A
handful of these intellectual-activists are still with us today; but, in the spirit of the new age, the most they
are now prepared to offer are passing and vague calls for the debt to be rescheduled.
Methodology
The study is based entirely on a trawl through secondary sources. The material used comes principally from
the South African Library and the library of the University of Cape Town. Time constraints made these
restrictions unavoidable. But the nature of the study itself, together with the richness of the secondary
sources, made original research unnecessary. This study is not an academic exercise so much as a policy
document of consideration and, hopefully, implementatio n. Technical complexities and what might be
considered to be “finer points” are generally out of place in an action-directed study. So, too, are references.
References will thus be kept to the best minimum and will be used only in instances where facts or
conclusions may be contentious or little known. Intellectual rigor, coherence and consistency are
nonetheless amongst the key criteria against which the document must be measured. These criteria are
especially important, because, as we need constantly to remind ourselves, the facts to which we anchor our
particular world views are invariably dismissed as false by those holding contrary views.
Style
Two objectives shape the style adopted. The first one is brevity. Length intimidates (most) people who have
been deprived of an adequate education. On the other hand, those who are comfortable with large amounts
of text are usually so busy keeping pace with the volume produced by the information age that lengthy
documents outside their narrow field tend to be put to one side.
Brevity dictates that, with one exception, the Report looks, in any depth, only at those areas where the
available material is scattered or where memory loss has been encouraged for ideological purposes. Marx
pg_0004
once apologized for having written a long letter because, he explained, he hadn’t the time to write a short
one. I intend making the time to avoid Marx’s problem.
3
The second objective regarding style is clarity. Here I can do no better than quote Beatrice Wright who
advised Eric Wright:
You must learn to write in such a way that it will be as easy as possible for your critics to know why
they disagree with you.
4
Apartheid’s Foreign Debt
Apartheid’s foreign debt refers to foreign loans and credits received before the establishment of the
Transitional Executive Council in December 1993 that have still to be repaid. A country gets into foreign
debt by borrowing from two elements: the national government and the private sector. Governments borrow
(a) from the he World Bank and foreign, private commercial banks in order to help pay for projects that they
cannot afford from their own resources; (b) from the International Monetary Fund (IF) when they don’t have
enough money — in internationally recognized currencies such as dollars — to pay for all the imports that
come into the country; and (c) through selling bonds on the international money markets. Private sector
borrowings are either for speculative money market purposes or for payment to foreign suppliers of
imported goods. Domestic banks are heavily involved in private sector borrowings. In South Africa these
borrowings consistently exceed those of the government.
Very few people seem to be concerned about our foreign debt nowadays. Could this apparent indifference
have anything to do with the size of the debt.
Size
Lack of attention to the foreign debt is almost certainly a (partial) consequence of what is perceived to be its
small size relative to the total public debt.
5
The approximate size of the total foreign debt at December 1993 was $20 billion. What is important to bear in
mind is that the debt is measured in US dollars even though some of the loans were issued in other
currencies. This means that over the years the rand’s devaluation against the dollar and the dollar’s decline
against currencies such as the German Mark and Swiss Franc greatly increase the size of the original debt.
The debt is currently just short of R90 billion.
Don’t Panic!
R90bn certainly sounds like a log of money. Most economists are not alarmed, however. Economis ts around
the world measure foreign debt in terms of the ratios of the debt to either gross domestic product (GDP) or
exports. The South African debt is well within what is considered to be acceptable limits.
— Unless You’re Poor
For South Africans deprived of the basic necessities of life — work; land; shelter; clean, potable water;
electricity; transport; education; health care, etc. — R90bn is somewhat more than an economic ratio about
which there is no need to lose any sleep. That most South Africans are, at best, inadequately covered by
these basic needs merely adds to the vital importance of R90bn, notwithstanding the economists who are so
sanguine about the foreign debt. R90,000,000,000 has so many noughts that it becomes a measure beyond
the scale of understanding for most of us. A comparison with the national budget for 1997-1998 and some
RDP costs should help make it easier to understand what all those noughts mean in practice, even though
the measures are not strictly comparable.
pg_0005
National Budget
The total national budget for 1997-1998 is R186,7 billion. The foreign debt of R90 billion represent almost half
what government ill spend this coming year.
Education - R40.2 bn
Health - R20.2 bn
Social Security & Welfare - 18.4
bn
Housing - 4.1 bn
Water - 1.8 bn
Interest - 38.5 bn
The interest on the total government debt, which is almost entirely debts incurred under apartheid, is 38.5
billion. The second largest expenditure item in the budget.
RDP estimates
The table below gives an idea what R90 billion can buy:
300,000 new homes - R10 bn
Electrification of 2.5 million homes - R11 bn over 5
years
Water and sanitation for 21 million people - R36 -
R56 bn over 5 years
1060 new clinics - R1.2 bn
Total cost to employ all unemployed - R82.8 bn per
annum
Upgrading 50,000 classrooms, rehabilitating 20,000
schools, building 77,000 new classrooms by the year
2000 and providing schools with textbooks R15 to
R17 bn
— Or Concerned About the Balance of Payments
Some mainstream economists do voice grave concern over one aspect of the foreign debt. The country is on
the brink of a balance of payments crisis. Current gold and foreign exchange reserves provide cover for only
about 1 month’s imports. Yet economist (including those who are happy with our debt ratios) accept that
reserves should cover at least 3 month’s worth of imports. The Government is scheduled to repay between
$1.5bn and $2.6b a year until 2001. $2.6 billion amount is due in 1997 unless roll-overs are negotiated.
6
Add the above (relatively small) debt repayments to the equation and South Africa faces the very real
prospect of a balance of payment crisis. The financial press reports on this looming problem from time to
time. The Government and its advisor s continue to play dumb, however.
— Or Alarmed by IMF Remedies
A balance of payments crisis, aggravated by foreign debt repayments, may push the government into the
arms of the IMF. IN this event, the cost of borrowing from the IMF, in order to pay for the trade deficit, may
well have to be acceptance of an IMF Structural Adjustment Program (SAP). If anything like other SAPs, the
surrender of our sovereignty to the IMF will make the lives of most South Africans even harder than at
present. This pint is revisited in due course.
pg_0006
A Problem in Need of a Remedy
What all this means is that the foreign debt is something only a few of us can afford to ignore and that it
takes self-protective blindness not to see the debt as a problem. Reaching this conclusion is only the first
step, however. The next — and bigger — challenge is to find an answer to what, if anything, can be done
about the matter.
Odious Debt
At a time when the anti-apartheid forces were at their strongest there was talk of unilateral repudiation of the
debt. However, even in those heady days, such talk was more posture than practical politics. Evidence for
this observation is that repudiation was never part of any program adopted by the ANC, UDF, COSATU,
the SACP. Indeed, no representative organization seems to have unambiguously adopted d ebt repudiation
as official policy.
In the changed climate of today’s South Africa, unilateral debt repudiation is not even a slogan. As
previously mentioned, the most one hears nowadays are calls for the debt to be renegotiated.
There is a third option, however. And that is to have the debt canceled by; international agreement. What is
more, a long- standing legal doctrine exits that allows for precisely this outcome.
The US Precedent
7
Almost 100 years ago, having used military might to seize control of Cuba from Spain, the US unilaterally
repudiated the debt Cuba had accumulated with Spain. The US justified its action by invoking what at the
time was still the somewhat vague Doctrine of Odious Debt. The US successfully argued that so the called
“Cuban debt” was unenforceable legally and morally because it had been
imposed upon the people of Cuba without their consent and by force of arms (and) was one of the
principal wrongs the termination of which the struggles for Cuban independence was undertaken.
The US further argued that much of the debt had been incurred for the purpose of crushing attempts by the
Cuban population to free themselves from Spanish domination. This made the objective of the debt contrary
to Cuba’s interest.
They are debts created by the Government of Spain, for its own purposes and through its own agents,
in whose creation Cuba had no voice.
For this reason, the debt could not be binding on the successor state, the US maintained.
As for the lenders, the US argued that
the creditors, from the beginning, took the chances of the investment. The very pledge of the national
credit, while it demonstrates on the one hand the national character of the debt, on the other hand
proclaims the notorious risk that attended the debt in its origin, and has attended it ever since.
8
The main burden of the US case was that the debt was unenforceable not because it imposed an excessive
burden on the successor state but because the debt was contracted for illegitimate purposes by illegitimate
parties.
The Bolshevik Revolution and the Codification of the Doctrine of Odious
Debt
The new Soviet government unequivocally decreed in 1918:
pg_0007
All foreign loans are hereby annulled without reserve or exception of any kind whatsoever.
9
Borrowing a central argument that the US had used so successfully in its claim that the Spanish debt was
odious, the Soviets maintained that the debts it inherited were the personal ones of the Tsar and his
government and could not, therefore, be transferred to the Soviet government.
This Soviet action was seen as a challenge to the integrity of international finance and the sanctity of
international law. According to this view, the Soviet action showed how the Doctrine of Odious Debt could
be abused by self-seeking interpretation. To avoid further instances of what was considered to be arbitrary
repudiation of debt, Alexander Nahum Sack, a former Minister of Tsarist Russia and, after the Russian
Revolution, a professor of law in Paris, wrote two major works on the obligations of successor systems: The
Effects of State Transformations on Their Public Debts and Other Financial Obligation and The
Succession of the Public Debts of the State.
Sack firmly upheld the general principal of the enforceability of public debts. Without strong rules enforcing
this principal chaos would reign in relations between nations, and international trade and finance would
break down. But Sack believed that debts not created in he interests of the state should not be bound by
this general rule. Some debts, he said, were “dettes odieuses.”
If a despotic power incurs a debt not for the needs or in the interest of the State, but to strengthen its
despotic regime, to repress the population that fights against it, etc., this debt is odious to the
population of the State.
This debt is not an obligation for the nation; it is a regime’s debt, a personal debt of the power that has
incurred it, consequently it falls with the fall of this power.
“Odious” debts, incurred and used for ends which, to the knowledge of the creditors, are contrary to
the interests of the nation do not…fulfill one of the conditions that determine the legality of the debts
of the State…The creditors have committed a hostile act with regard to the people; they can’t therefore
expect that a nation freed from a despotic power assume the “odious” debts, which are the personal
debts of that power.
10
Sack proposed that henceforth Governments invoking the Doctrine of Odious Debt would be required to
prove that the debt ill-served the public interest and that the creditors were aware of this Sack declared:
When a government incurs bets to subjugate the population of a part of its territory or to colonize it
with members of the dominant nationality, etc., these debts are odious to the indigenous
population…
11
Provided these proofs were met by the successor government, the onus would be on the creditors to show
that the funds were utilized for the benefit of the country. If the creditors could not do so, before an
international tribunal, the debt would be unenforceable.
A clear precedent, based on Sack’s submissions, was provided by Chief Justice Taft of the US Supreme
Court. Sitting as arbitrator in the 1923 case, Great Britain vs. Costa Rica, Chief Justice Taft upheld the Costa
Rican Law of Nulleties. This law, passed by the successor government to the dictatorship of President
Tinoco, drew on the Doctrine of Odious Debt to repudiate the debts entered into between the fallen dictator
and the Royal Bank of Canada. Chief Justice Taft’s ruling decided:
The transactions in questions…were made at a time when the popularity of the Tinoco Government had
disappeared, and when the political and military movement aiming at the overthrow of that Government
was gaining strength…The case of the Royal Bank depends not on the mere form of the transaction but
upon the good faith of the bank…It must make out its case of actual furnishing the money to the
government for its legitimate use. It has not done so…The Royal Bank of Canada cannot be deemed to
have proved that the payments were made for legitimate government use. Its claim must fail.
12
In 1982, lawyers at The First National Bank of Chicago warned lenders of about making loans that ran the
risk of falling foul of Odious Debt Doctrines and precedents. They reminded financial institutions that:
pg_0008
The consequences of a change of sovereignty for loan agreements may depend in part on the use of
the loan proceeds by the predecessor state. If the debt of the predecessor is deemed to be “odious,”
i.e., the debt proceeds are used against the interests of the local populace, then the debt may not be
chargeable to the successor
13.
The lawyers warned that although the intended use of loans or credits is usually indicated in bank loan
agreements the use described is often too general to ensure that the loan benefited the people and thus
ensure the enforcement of the debt repayment. The lawyers drew further attention to the fact that the loan
documents rarely restrict the money’s use. The accordingly advised:
Commercial banks should be alert to the danger of […Odious Debt Doctrines]. Because successor
governments have invoked doctrines based on an “odious” or “hostile” use of the proceeds, lenders
should describe with specificity the uses of the loans proceeds and, if possible, bind the borrower by
representation, warranty, and covenant to those uses
14
.
In her exposition of the Doctrine of Odious Debt, Patricia Adams concludes with an observation that is
particularly germane for the apartheid debt:
Lenders who finance the arming or enrichment of despotic rulers and the suppression of popular
insurrections — as the Spaniards discovered with their Cuban debts — have no guarantees of
protection from international law…For years bankers have not exercised the vigilance that would make
state debts lawful. The consequences could be breathtaking: the Chase Manhattans, Lloyds and Ex-Im
banks might find that their Third World loans were uncollectable, except from the personal estates of
the Marcoses and the Mobutus who contracted them
15
.
The Stench of the Apartheid Debt
The Doctrine of Odious Debt arose centuries before formal apartheid and underwent its development in
jurisprudence without the slightest recognition of apartheid. Yet the Doctrine matches the circumstances of
the apartheid state so perfectly that is almost as though Odious Debt was established in law with the
express purpose of allowing the first democratic government in South Africa to repudiate the apartheid debt
it inherited.
The Doctrine has two main aspects, as we have just seen: the legitimacy of t he borrower’s purpose in
seeking the loan and whether the lender was recklessly indifferent to the status of the contracting state.
Both of these aspects warrant closer examination contextualized in apartheid South Africa.
(I) The Illegitimacy of Apartheid
The question whether a loan was sought for legitimate purposes has an entirely unequivocal answer during
the apartheid era. No loan could have had a legitimate purpose during the apartheid years because apartheid
itself was illegitimate. Moreover the ille gitimacy of apartheid was affirmed and repeatedly re-affirmed by
every relevant international forum. The United Nations (UN) and the International Court of Justice (ICJ)
were the most significant of the international bodies that pronounced on the illegitimacy of the apartheid
state. Beginning in 1973, the UN repeatedly found apartheid to be a crime against humanity. The apartheid
sate was additionally a persistent and extensive violator of a least for legally entrenched international
obligations. These obligations were:
Self Determination
In 1970 the General Assembly (GA) of the UN unanimously adopted the Declaration on Principles of
International Law Concerning Friendly Relations & Co -operation among States in Accordance with the
Charter of the United Nations (hereinafter referred to as the Declaration on Friendly Relations). In terms of
this Declaration all member states agree that self-determination is a legal right with corresponding legal
obligations:
pg_0009
…all peoples have the right freely to determine, wit hout external interference, their political status and
to pursue their economic, social and cultural development, and every sate has a duty to respect this
right in accordance with the provisions of the Charter.
16
The Declaration defines the right of self-determination as, inter ail, the right of people in independent and
sovereign states to be ruled by a
…government representing the whole people belonging to the territory without distinction as to race,
creed or colour.
The blank majority in apartheid South Africa constituted a “people” for purposes of self-determination. It
accordingly follows that, as long as black South Africans were denied the right to determine their own
political future, the apartheid state failed to fulfill its legal obligations in respect of self-determination.
(b) Human Rights
The UN Charter binds member states to promote and encourage respect for human rights.17 The Charter
further imposes a legal obligation on member states to take joint and separate action to promote
…universal re spect for, and observance of human rights and fundamental freedoms for all without
distinction as to race, sex, language or religion.
18
The human rights member states are pledged to observe are set out in the Universal Declaration of Human
Rights of 1948. Apartheid deliberately and explicitly violated many of these rights, especially the human
right not to be discriminated against on the grounds of race and color. As the International Court of Justice
(ICJ) observed in the case in which it found that South A frica was in illegal occupation of Namibia:
To establish…and to enforce distinctions, exclusions, restrictions and limitations exclusively on the
grounds of race, color, descent or national or ethnic origin, which constitute a denial of fundamental
human rights, is a flagrant violation of the purposes and principles of the UN Charter.
19
(c) Destabilization of Southern Africa
Article 2(4) of the UN Charter requires states to refrain from the threat of use of force in their international
relations. Article 2(4) further prohibits the following state conduct, according to the General Assemble (GA)
of the UN:
Organizing or encouraging the organization of irregular forces or armed bands, including mercenaries,
for incursion into the territory of another State
…Organizing, instigating, assisting or participating in acts of civil strife or terrorist acts in another State
or acquiescing in organized activities within its territory directed towards the commission of such
acts…
20
Moreover, the ICJ has held that the assistance to rebel forces in the form of the provision of weapons
constitutes a threat or use of force in terms of Article 2(4).21 South Africa’s destabilization of its
neighboring States is well documented.22 In view of the fact that the General Assembly has authoritatively
interpreted Article 2(4) to prohibit a state’s forcible denial of the right of self-determination, the apartheid
regime’s violent repression of the struggle constitutes an instance of the prohibited use of force.
(d) The Rule of Non-Intervention
A state acts contrary to the legal prohibition of intervention when it applies, inter alia, economic coercion to
force another state to take action it has a sovereign right to refrain from taking. The apartheid regime’s illegal
economic assault on states in southern Africa took the form of trade and transport boycotts, unreasonable
border checks to delay the passage of goods, as well as embargoes on food, oil and other exports to these
states.23
pg_0010
Fergusson-Brown concludes his closely argued research with t he observation:
The effect of these persistent violations by South Africa of its legal obligations is clear: they constitute
a flagrant disregard for international law, undermine the authority of the UN and seriously threaten
international peace and security. As such they present a challenge to the international community.
24
(II) The Illegitimacy of Loans to South Africa
Recall that Sack’s contribution to the systematization of the Doctrine of Odious Debt was to require a new
government to prove that the foreign loans were contrary to the public interest and that the creditors were
aware of this. Having established these criteria, the burden of proof then moved to the creditors: they would
have to persuade an international tribunal that the funds were utilized for the benefit of the people as a
whole, as opposed to a self-serving and unaccountable elite. The debt would be unenforceable unless the
creditors were able to do this.
No foreign loan granted to South Africa during the apartheid years could have been legitimate because the
apartheid sate was itself illegitimate; and any attempt to claim ignorance of this fact would not be credible.
This single circumstance means that, with only one very limited exception (the 1993 IMF loan to the
Transitional Executive Council), no foreign lender would have a valid claim against democratic South Africa
for any loans outstanding from the apartheid years. Nonetheless, the creditors’ inability to enforce any
claims against post-apartheid South Africa is even more overwhelming.
International loans to South Africa came from three sources: the World Bank/International Monetary Fund
(IMF), private commercial banks and high-risk-speculators. In developing the argument of the
unenforceability of the foreign debt, over and above the fact of the illegitimacy of apartheid itself, it is
convenient to examine these three sources in turn.
(a) World Bank/IMF
None of South Africa’s existing foreign debt is with the World Bank, South Africa having discharged all it
loan obligations to the World Bank in 1976. Since then, the World Bank has had to reclassify South Africa
as a donor rather than a recipient country, a reclassification made necessary on the basis of South Africa’s
per capita GDP.
Between 1946-47, however, South Africa received 11 World Bank loans, the last of which were made in 1966-
67. Seven of these loans were in support of the country’s transport system. The remaining four loans were
to ESKOM for improvements and extensions to the electricity grids.
25
The military significance of the
improved transport network should be noted. So, too, should the fact that the improvements to the
electricity grids had nothing to do with supplying power to black South Africans.
World Bank loans to South Africa far exceeded those received by any other African country during the
period 1946-47. Only Nigeria cane even close to matching the level of World Bank support to South Africa.
The total value of South African loans indeed compared favorably with countries like France & Holland.
26
The World Bank indirectly assisted the apartheid regime after the time when South Africa was no longer
eligible for direct World Bank loans. The World Bank (along with the British and US governments) rejected
the Tanzanian and Zambian Government’s request for funds to build the Tanzanian railroad to reduce
Zambian dependence on South Africa (and white-ruled Rhodesia). The World Bank argued that Zambia
already had adequate rail links through South Africa. The World Bank also refused to finance construction
of a railway or tarmac road from Botswana directly to Zambia to enable Botswana to transport copper to
Zambia’s smelters. The Bank asserted that there was no need for such a direct route as access was already
available via South Africa.
27
The IMF’s relationship with South Africa was one in which the apartheid state enjoyed a long and very
favorable position. This special relationship came to an end in 1983 when the US government imposed a
veto on all further IMF loans. Escape from this veto was possible only if the US Secretary of the Treasury
pg_0011
certified in person before the IMF’s decision-making committee that the loan would reduce the distortions of
apartheid. In acting thus the US government was belatedly responding to the influence of anti-apartheid
forces within the US.
The great proportion of IMF loans to South Africa were made after 1970 and was heavily concentrated in the
period between the mid -1970s and 1982. Until the IMF was forced to stop loans to South Africa, only
Yugoslavia received more IMF assistance than South Africa amongst the IMF-classified sub-group of
“major exporters of manufactures” among non-oil developing countries.
28
IMF assistance to South Africa in
the two years 1976-77 was in fact greater than the combined assistance to all other African countries for the
same period. In those two years only Britain and Mexico were bigger recipients of IMF support.
29
There
were two IMF loans in 1976; in January and November. Arguing in support of the January loan, the British
government saw its importance being that it
would give the (South African) authorities…some feeling of international support which they
deserve.
30
The November loan, of course, came only five months after the Soweto uprising. The loan, strongly
criticized by several countries, was granted with the heavily weighted support of the US and Britain.
In 1981, with the gold price plummeting and imports surging (in part because of increasing militarization),
South Africa once again ran up a deficit on the current account of the balance of payments. The So uth
African authorities approached the IMF for a loan of $1.1 billion in mid -1982. Acting on US advice the
approach was not made public until October that year; the delay being a tactical one to better manage the
expected opposition to the approach. Sixty-eight countries did indeed subsequently oppose the loan while a
further nine countries called for its postponement. The US, Canada, and the major West European countries,
the small block with the majority voting rights, backed the loan. The loan was approved.
31
Later that year, in
June, a report submitted by the IMF’s own staff was critical of apartheid on economic grounds. This critique
of apartheid was the first in the IMF’s history.
32
The report led directly to the US imposing its previously
mentioned veto on further IMF loans to South Africa.
33
The 1982 loan was repaid in full by 1986.
One the eve of the new South Africa, in December 1993, the IMF granted its first new loan in more than 11
years. The loan, for $850 million, was approved by the ANC through t he short-lived Transitional Executive
Council. Repayment is due to commence in March 1997 and will be in 8 equal quarterly installments. ANC
endorsement of the loan complicates what is otherwise the clear-cut case of the odiousness of IMF loans to
apartheid South Africa. IN assessing whether, or to what extent, this 1993 loan is odious, regard should be
had of the undoubted odiousness of loans that have already been paid off. Due consideration should also
be given to the part played by the IMF in its deliberate protection of apartheid, prior to the 1983 US veto.
In this respect — and in addition to the preceding points — regard must be had of the IMF’s role as
advisor, salesman and sanctions buster to and for the apartheid regime. IMF economists visited South
Africa in 1975 to advise on the regime’s rising indebtedness. The IMF approved the subsequent reforms
even though it called for even more unrestrained rights for capital (so-called liberalization), including having
the rand as a free-floating currency. The IMF applauded the scrapping of the financial rand in 1983 and was
directly involved in the design and introduction of VAT in 1991.
34
The racial dictatorship’s good standing with the IMF, prior to 1983, helps explain why 20% of all
transnational bank loans to African states went to South Africa.
35
A country that wins the IMF seal of
approval invariably attracts capital from other sources. This connection is well established and is of
universal applicability. Between December 1981 and September 1984, transnational loans to South Africa
doubled from $9.9 billion to $19 bn.
36
The IMF’s sanctions-busting took the form of insisting, in 1980, that Zambia reopen its trade routes with
South Africa, as a precondition for IMF assistance.
pg_0012
The IMF/World Bank might seek to argue that, as banks, they were merely acting in accordance with their
understanding of the then prevailing best economic practices. For them to have done anything more would
have been a transgression into political matter from which they were precluded by their own charters. They
could not sustain this argument, however. Their repeated interference in the politics of a large number of
different countries around the world is a matter of well-established record.
A question arises from the role of the World Bank/IMF as a loyal and substantial ally of the racial
dictatorship over many generations: are these two principal institutions of international finance morally
bound to return all the money that has already been paid in settlement of previous debts. As we have seen,
other than $750 million that is due for repayment, beginning 1997, all World Bank/IMF debts have been
settled. The possibility of having the debt settlement money returned to the new South Africa is fully in
keeping with the spirit of Odious Debt even though it might appear to lie outside the strict letter of the
Doctrine. As we have seen, other than the $750 million that is due for repayment, beginning this year, all
other World Bank/IMF loans have already been repaid. The question that arises is whether these two
principal institutions of international finance are morally bound to return all this repaid money to the new
South Africa.
(b) Private Commercial Banks
The role of the Banks in actively defending apartheid is clearly illustrated by the three rescheduling
agreements made with the apartheid regime between 1986-1993 following the Government’s unilateral
freezing of (part of) its foreign debt in 1985.
The immediate background to the foreign debt crisis of 1985 was as follows: On the 20th o f July 1985, after
10 months of almost continuous unrest in the then Transvaal and the Eastern Cape, the government
declared a State of Emergency in 36 magisterial districts and detained hundreds of anti-apartheid activists. A
few days later the French government announced restrictions on French investments in South Africa. IN the
week following the State of Emergency the market value of shares on the Johannesburg Stock Exchange
(JSE) fell be R11 billion. Brokers described the wave of selling, mainly by US, UK & French shareholders, as
a “bloodbath”.
37
In the same week there were rumors that Chase Manhattan Bank, Citibank and others would refuse to renew
short -term loans to South Africa, many of which were to fall due at the end of August. On July 31st, Chase
Manhattan announced that it would neither extend credit on maturing short -term loans to South African
borrowers, nor advance credit to South African new private borrowers. The next day Chase Manhattan’s
lead was taken up by the Security Pacific Corporatio n with other US banks following the same path during
August.
On August 15th, P.W. Botha delivered his widely anticipated “Rubicon” speech. But, in place of the reforms
the public had been led to expect, he offered only more repression at home and bitterly attached the
“interference” coming from abroad. The rand fell 20% on the Johannesburg foreign exchange the next
morning. The government suspended all trading on the JSE and in foreign exchange on August 27th, after
the rand had reached a then record low of $0.35. The Governor of the Reserve Bank flew to London, New
York & Washington to negotiate relief, but his mission was fruitless. On September 2nd, the day before the
exchanges reopened in South Africa, the government announced a (partial) debt moratorium.
38
International pressure on the banks built up quickly and steadily. Punitive action against South Africa was
urged. Alternatively, the banks were recommended to require major political reforms as the price for allowing
the apartheid regime to renegotiate its debt. The banks felt sufficiently exposed for them not to wish to be
seen to be negotiating directly with the odious regime. They, therefore, accepted the South African
Government’s proposal of mediation by Fritz Leutwiler whose banking credentials were as impeccable as his
record for acting on non-commercial considerations was wanting. Leutwiler was the former President of
Switzerland’s central bank and Chairman of the Bank of International Settlements, a “body which in many
respects acts as the central bank to central bankers”.
39
At the time of his appointment, he was the head of
the Swiss industrial multinational, Brown Boveri.
pg_0013
The committee established to negotiate the debt met for the first time in London in October 1985. A second
London meeting scheduled for November was canceled, apparently due to political pressure. In December,
Archbishop Tutu, the Rev. Alan Boesak and the Rev. Beyers Naude called on the banks not to reschedule
the debt unless fundamental political reforms were first undertaken b y the government.
40
Even before this
call, the Governor of the Reserve Bank, Dr. de Kock, admitted that tangible evidence of political reform was a
precondition for the debt rescheduling. He
hinted that this message has finally reached the Government after direct warnings from Dr. Fritz
Leutwiler.
41
Like the South African Government, and amidst a growing clamor for change from leading sections of South
African business, the banks, too, appeared to accept the need for substantial political reform if public
opinion in their own countries was to be appeased. As early as the 29th of August 1985, the Guardian noted
“a considerable consensus” amongst British bankers and business leaders typified by the statement that
Political rights for Africans are now on the agenda. In the past you could have talked about social
rights or human rights alone. That is no longer enough.
Similarly, in announcing Barclays’ results for 1985, the Group’s Chairman announced that the Bank wanted
changes which confirm an end tot he bankrupt political institution of racial discrimination
and expected
the release of the imprisoned black leader, Nelson Mandela, as a sign of good faith.
After the disaster of Botha’s “Rubicon” speech of the previous August, much was expected of “Rubicon
II,” Botha’s second attempt to match the requirements of the new political and economic realities. The banks
did their best to make the most of Rubicon II when it was delivered in January 1986. But even mainstream
Western commentators were not deceived. The Financial Times, for instance, carried an article entitled
“Botha aims to modernize apartheid, not kill it.”
42
Any doubts about the intentions of Rubicon II would
have been dispelled by Botha himself when he criticized his Foreign Minister for saying that apartheid was
being dismantled and that a black President was foreseeable.
Botha’s antics allowed the anti-apartheid forces to up the ante. The strongest action open to the banks to
recover their unilaterally frozen debts would have been the freezing of South Africa’s assets abroad. This
strategy was indeed proposed by Tutu, Naude and Boesak. They wrote to Dr. Leutwiler, in February 1986
proposing
that the banks should immediately freeze all South African bank balances in their books and refuse to
effect any transfer instructions over these accounts.
They further suggested
that the banks…obtain court attachment of aircraft, ships and other South African assets and apply the
proceeds against South African indebtedness.
Such asset freezes had already been applied els ewhere by governments, notably those of Britain and the
US. Moreover, the asset freezing could have covered the debt without even having to seize the ships and
aircraft mentioned by the clerics.
43
The pressure on the banks was thus enormous. They were also the innocent party in the South African
government’s reneging on its debt commitments. They were, therefore, well placed not to rescue the
apartheid regime. Yet that is precisely what they did. The terms of the First Interim Agreement, of February
1986, could hardly have been kinder to the racial dictatorship. Archbishop Trevor Huddleston, President of
the Anti-Apartheid Movement, condemned Dr. Leutwiler as being “little more than a mouthpiece for Botha.”
Neil Kinnock, Leader of the Opposition in Britain, described the decision to postpone the bulk of the
repayments as being of “great assistance and encouragement to President Botha.”
44
pg_0014
This first “Interim Arrangement” covered the period from March 1986 6o the end of June 1987, at which
point the apartheid government would have to renegotiate the payment of the remainder of the outstanding
frozen debt.
The State of Emergency that was lifted shortly before the first agreement was reached was reimposed with
far greater rigor, within months of the agreement having been signed. Less than four months after
negotiations for the First Interim Arrangement had been completed, the accord was openly thrown into
question when Dr. Worral, the South African Ambassador to the UK, threatened that his government might
renege on the agreement and default. The regime repeated this threat a month later, when the
Commonwealth leaders agreed to more wide-ranging trade sanctions.
One might have expected such bad faith by the apartheid government to be reflected in a second agreement
with the now chastened bakers being far less accommodating of South Africa than they had been in the first
agreement had been. Yet, the Second Interim Arrangement, announced in March 1987, surprised even the
South African ruling circles by its forgiving character. All pretense of reform was dropped; the international
bankers made no political demands whatsoever. Howard Preece, the Deputy Editor of the South African
business journal, Finance Week, noted that the relationship between South African and international
bankers was almost back to its normal state of coziness. He pointed out that the return to normalcy was so
complete that even Dr. Leutwiler had not been required to play the intermediary role in securing the second
agreement. Preece observed that both the Finance Minister and the Governor of the Reserve Bank were fully
justified in calling the agreement a “great day” for South Africa.
45
If the Second Interim Arrangement was a “great” achievement for apartheid, the Third Interim Arrangement,
announced on the 18th of October 1989, was an occasion for the regime’s disbelieving celebration. The
negotiations took place at a time when the apartheid state was most exposed financially and when the
international anti-apartheid movements were at their most powerfu l.
46
Eight billion dollars was due for repayment when the Second Arrangement expired at the end of June 1990.
In addition, a significant amount of the debt that had not been frozen in 1985 was scheduled to fall due in
the same period. For this reason, supporters of financial sanctions saw mid -1990 as a critical opportunity for
maximizing pressure on the South African government.
US Congressmen set 7 condition for rescheduling the debt: ending the state of emergency; releasing all
political prisoners; lifting of the ban on all political organization; allowing the return of political exiles and
refugees; restoring Press freedom; repealing all apartheid legislation; establishing a process to negotiating a
new constitution for democratic, non-racial and unitary South Africa.
47
Eight Commonwealth Foreign Ministers agreed, in August 1989, to put pressure on banks to impose
stringent repayment terms on the $12 billion they were owed by South Africa in an attempt to end apartheid.
The action, designed to coincide with South Africa’s need to renegotiate its debt by June 1990, was agreed
to at a meeting of the Commonwealth Committee of Foreign Ministers on South Africa. The Committee
Chairman, Canada’s Joe Clark, told reporters
We want to exert the most stringent possible pressure on South Africa at a critical time.
48
The South Africa Coalition, formed in September 1989, served to coordinate all anti-apartheid struggles in
Britain. All the nine main churches in Britain as well as bodies such as Oxfam and Friends of the Eart h were
part of this coalition of some 70 organization. The Coalition’s Chairman, Simon Barrington-Ward, the Bishop
of Coventry, warned the apartheid regime to expect “major pressure” when trying to reschedule its foreign
debt.
49
ELTSA (End Loans to South Africa) was launched in early October 1989 to spearhead the international
campaign against the rescheduling of the regime’s foreign debts.
50
On the eve of the Commonwealth Conference, in mid -October 1989, Sonny Ramphal, the secretary -general,
called for united action to pressure the banks holding South Africa’s debt.
51
pg_0015
The UN added its voice to the pressure on the banks. The main thrust of its resolution, “International
Financial Pressure on the Apartheid Economy of South Africa,” noted
Considering that the rescheduling of South Africa’s external debt at this particular time represents an
attempt to undermine the efforts of the international community to promote a peaceful resolution of the
conflict in that country…Strongly urges governments and private financial institutions to deny new
bank loans to South Africa, whether to the public or private sectors.
52
Requirements that focused much more narrowly on the technical side of the debt itself included delaying
completion of the negotiations until just before the June 30th 1990 deadline in order to keep pressure on
F.W. de Klerk, who had only recently been elected the new President,
53
restricting the life of the new
arrangement to no more than one year,
54
and charging the highest possible interest rates.
55
The Third In terim Arrangement was announced on the 18th of October 1989. This made it some eight
months earlier than it need have been. (It was also some four months before the unbanning of the ANC and
other political parties and the release of Mandela.) Instead of being restricted to the called for maximum of
one year it was to run for three and a half years, thus making it the longest of the three arrangements. Only
19% of the outstanding debt was required to be paid during this extended period. The Arrangement
contained none of the provisions sought by the international organizations acting on behalf of the “public
good” by representing the disenfranchised majority of South Africans.
The ANC condemned the Arrangement describing it as an act of “inhumanity” whose purpose was that
of helping perpetuate the evil system of apartheid…When the time comes, the South African people will
not be unmindful of the role of banks in making profit out of the misery of our people.
56
Even the US government described the Arrangement as being “particularly favorable to South Africa.
57
The part played by international banks is actively supporting apartheid includes three additional aspects
which are worthy of note: the composition of the foreign debt, correspondent banking and trade credits.
Short -term inter-bank loans had become the dominant form of foreign capital by 1985. Direct, long-term risk
capital investments declined in proportion to the deepening crisis facing apartheid after 1976; the risks were
considered to be too high for long-term investment. On the other hand, short -term loans offered foreign
banks profitability with the perception of acceptable risk. The transformation of South Africa’s debt from
long-term to short -term was dramatic. Thus the proportion of the country’s foreign debt with an unexpired
maturity of less than one year rose from 49% at the end of 1980 to 68% in 1984 and to 72% by the end of
1985.
58
By the time of the August 1985 debt crisis, 85% of all US loans to South Africa were short term.
59
Short -term debts accounted for over three-quarters of South Africa’s total foreign debt in 1990.
60
For the apartheid regime as well as their willing bankers, a major attraction of the short -term loans was their
anonymity; transactions on the inter-bank credit markets are never published. Short -term loans thus allowed
banks to trade freely with the apartheid state without third parties’ knowledge. For this reason, short -term
loans were an ideal sanctions-buster.
The difficulty in tracing short -term loans — even the conservative (British) Daily Telegraph described them
as “a near perfect disguise.”
61
Together with the instability of the long-term loans as the struggle against
apartheid intensified, made inter-bank transactions highly attractive to both borrower and lender and
accounts for the unusually high ratio of short- to long-term debt in South Africa. The South African ratio, at
the end of June 1984, was some 22% higher than in comparable developed countries.
62
It was an open secret that the banks who were victims of the apart heid regime’s reneging on its debts were
the same banks that nonetheless continued to supply the interbank credit used by South Africa to breach
sanctions with impunity. Furthermore, the financial institution used to facilitate international payments —
the Brussels based Society for Worldwide Interbank Financial Telecommunications (SWIFT) — allowed the
pg_0016
odious regime to enjoy the full benefits of membership despite procedures available for expelling member
banks. The US Assistant Comptroller General, commenting on this last point in 1990, observed:
Even though it would be difficult to effectively exclude South African banks from SWIFT…, barring
them from […SWIFT] might have the symbolic effect of excluding South Africa from yet another
international system.
63
Apartheid South Africa was indeed expelled from the international financial institution that facilitates
international payments. This New York based body, the Clearing House Interbank Payments System
(CHIPS), served 139 national and international depository institutions and processed transfers valued at
$165 trillion in 1988. Nedbank was admitted to CHIPS in 1984 but was asked to leave in 1986. Its expulsion
made no difference however because of the help given by other member banks. Thanks to these
“correspondent” banks apartheid South Africa continued to have its accounts maintained and its dollar
transactions processed, notwithstanding its formal expulsion.
Trade credits provided another life -line for apartheid.
64
Trade credits provided South Africa with a major
form of new credit at a time when international banks were supposedly severing, or at least restricting, ties
with the international outcast. Trade credits add mightily to the weakness of the banks’ case in any action
they might bring to enforce their claims against democratic South Africa for debts accrued during the
apartheid years. Most of the banks that declared they would end loans to South Africa explicitly excluded
trade credits from the ban.
The bulk of South Africa’s trade, which in the late 80s amounted to between $10bn and $12bn per year, was
financed through trade credits. Indeed, at least 25% of those credits were actually guaranteed by the export
credit organizations of foreign Governments. Trade credits played a critical role in the international credit
structure of the apartheid state. Not only did they make it possible to import products, including capital
goods for expansion, but they allowed long-term borrowing to take place. It is for these reasons that the
Governor of the Reserve Bank exhorted importers to use foreign credit during difficult foreign exchange
periods. It is for these reasons too that he made special arrangements to cheapen the cost of the foreign
credit, in order to bring in the foreign capital, however small and for however short a time.
65
The last words
on the importance of trade credits to the odious regime belong to its Director of Finance, Dr. Chris Stals:
If the world banking community should effectively exclude South Africa from international trade and
payments s ystems, it would be a much more effective sanctions measure than trade sanctions applied
by governments.
66
(c) High-risk Speculators
Individual investors (and a number of speculative financial institutions) were the third source of loans
drawn on by the apartheid regime. It was the very odiousness of apartheid that made investment attractive
for this group. Facing mounting political turmoil at home, while being out of favor with the international
community and having reneged on its debt with the large, mainstream banks, the apartheid state was forced
to borrow expensive money from a source that was willing to make loans, at above market rates, to anyone.
Hirsch notes dryly:
Neither the crisis over the unilateral freezing of debts nor the political turmoil in the country put a stop
to high risk money coming into South Africa. The crisis meant that the cost of foreign money went up
and that all transactions were kept secret. The volume of loans was reduced, however; but, at some
R800m in 1987 alone, the volume was not insubstantial… Small private banks in Switzerland, the Federal
Republic of Germany and the Benelux countries are known to be involved in gathering finance for South
Africa, often through hidden complex deals.
67
Piecing together the scattered and difficult to obtain information reveals the following deals: December 1988
— a small Swiss private bond of $37m; 1989 — three small Swiss private bonds totaling $128m and a German
pg_0017
private placement for ESCOM; 1990 — seven German private placements raising a total of $264m; 1991 —
eight bond issues, five of which are know to have come from Germany, totaling $554m.
68
The Deputy Editor of the Finance Week was commendably candid when referring to the “hot” money
making its way into the apartheid state. He noted approvingly:
Foreign bankers are remembering that ultimately they are money-lenders not moralists. They are noting
that profitable business can still be done with South Africa.
69
(d) Apartheid-Contamination of all Loans
To say that no loans made during the apartheid years could have been legitimate warrants further, brief
explication. Desegregation of the debt — the ability to specify who lent what, to whom, and for what
purpose — requires far greater research than was possible here. What can be said, however, is that
apartheid generated its own enormous and varied costs.
70
To the costs of the inefficiencies and
duplications of apartheid must be added those of defending the system. The Sharpeville Massacre of 1960
resulted in the militarization of the state, a transformation that grew at a phenomenal pace after the Soweto
Uprising of 1976. Sanctions-busting, together with its corollary of stock-piling, was also enormously
expensive. Foreign loans helped pay for all these costs in a multitude of ways, any of which might appear to
have nothing to do with apartheid.
A large number of the inter-bank loans, for instance, had no direct connection with apartheid. Yet, the
foreign exchange given for a seemingly innocuous purpose — ranging from the development of ESKOM
71
to t he financing of a domestic home
72
— was recycled as part of apartheid’s sanctions-busting strategy.
Similarly, some foreign loans were used for purposes of international trade and, in this respect, were no
different from those regularly found throughout the world. Yet, even the seemingly most pristine of these
trade loans were tainted by apartheid. The simple fact of trade with South Africa inescapably meant helping
to sustain and reproduce the structures, practices and life -styles normalized by apartheid. No loan could
avoid this institutional contamination.
Negotiating the Debt Cancellation
A Notable Precedent
A modern precedent does exist whereby a government freely canceled a debt owed it and did so purely
because of the immorality of the debt which it canceled in full. What is more, this government canceled the
debt on its own initiative and evidently without even being aware of the Doctrine of Odious Debt. The
government in question is, of course, that of democratic South Africa and the debt (of R1.242 billion
73
) was
that inherited by the government of democratic Namibia.
The Limits of Debate
The point to emphasize about the strategy being proposed here is that it rests, in the first place, on a
negotiated recognition of the odiousness of the apartheid debt. This is to say, the cancellation of the debt
would be the ideal outcome of multi-lateral negotiations between the new South African government and the
foreign creditors from the apartheid period.
74
The powerful persuasiveness of the argument that the apartheid debt is odious in the extreme and therefore
unenforceable would not be the only consideration behind the negotiated debt cancellation. The new South
Africa is in many ways a miracle and the hopes and good wishes of a huge body of people around the world
are pinned on the miracle surviving and seeding a transformative development and reconstruction of the
pg_0018
country that significantly touches the lives of all South Africans. Moreover, as part of the miracle, South
Africa has a leader revered throughout the world. Mandela’s stature is unique in modern times. For these
various reasons, South Africa could approach the negotiations with great confidence.
75
However, it must be accepted that, even if the banks were to be sympathetic to the case of Mandela’s South
Africa, the debt is arguably not of a size that can easily be lost in the intricacies of the banks’ bookkeeping.
And, certainly no less important, the banks would be mindful of the precedent that might be set if the
arguments of the democratic South Africa were to be accepted. Precedent would not be an issue if South
Africa was alone in having inherited a debt burden. But this is not the case. A large number of other
countries would be watching the negotiations very closely and would not be disinterested in the outcome.
In situations of conflicting interests, reason and justice seldom have a look in when it comes to the final
decision-making. Nor does the weight of evidence or the cogency with which the case is presented. Thus far
I world history, the conflicts of real life, especially those involving the material interests of large numbers of
people, are rarely settled according to the standards of a debating society.
Recognition of this reality shapes the specificity’s of the strategy.
International Solidarity
Only Vietnam and South Africa have attracted solidarity action that could accurately be described as
international and mass-based. Vietnam comes a remote second when compared with the number and
diversity of the people mobilized against apartheid. The anti-apartheiders, in all continents of the world,
would form a natural constituency for solidarity action designed to encourage the banks to be reasonable
according to criteria wider than narrow commercial interest.
The size of the debt, together with the fear of the precedent any cancellation would set, virtually guarantees
the involvement of the Governments of the countries in which the banks are (nominally) based. At the end
of 1990, 87% of South Africa’s outstanding debt was owed to the banks of 5 countries in descending order,
they were Britain, Germany, France, the US and Switzerland. British banks accounted for 26.8% of all bank
debts, whereas Switzerland, the fifth largest creditor, accounted for 11.8%.
76
Solidarity action must
accordingly expect to be directed at those Government’s that might oppose the cancellation of the debt.
A brief comment on the complicity of these Governments in the creation, development and defense of what
came to be known as apartheid is therefore apposite. An understanding of the role of the West as an
accomplice of apartheid would be an important component of the solidarity action expected by a broad-
based movement in those countries.
Internationalizing Affirmative Action and Truth & Reconciliation
Action is very much a feature of contemporary South Africa and forms a prominent part of government
policy.
Internationally — and especially in those countries which have had a long experience of their own
Affirmative Action programs — Affirmative Action is viewed much more critically than in South Africa.
What can be said about the practice of Affirmative Action everywhere is that it has come to mean
Affirmative ethnicising class-mobility for an elite amongst those previously disadvantaged by racism. Color-
coded affirmative action reinforces pre -existing racism, encourages the formation of new “ethnic” groups,
discriminates against mainly innocent members of the previously privileged “race” who, in the main being
young, have not enjoyed the preferential employment opportunities that marked the previous order — and it
leaves untouched the lives of the vast majority of those who inherited the inequalities Affirmative Action is
supposed to redress.
On the other hand, the logic behind the theory of Affirmative Action is impeccable: the disadvantages and
inequities endured by people formerly subject to institutionalized racism will naturally reproduce
themselves, even when all forms of discrimination have officially been outlawed, unless imposed
pg_0019
interventions are made by the newly non-racial state. The Reconstruction & Development Program (RDP),
even in the much watered down version in which it now appears, exemplifies the depth and range of state
interventions required to establish some semblance of equality amongst South Africans. The RDP seeks to
provide the infrastructural necessities of life that, under apartheid, were the exclusive prerogative of the
white dictatorship and its handful of black surrogates in the Bantustans and Tri-cameral Parliament.
Affirmative Action is theoretically a form of reparation, a recognition by the group previously privileged by
apartheid of the wrongs done, of the enormous debt owed to those who suffered the crimes of apartheid.
Western Governments — and especially those representing the banks most heavily involved in apartheid
— were themselves more than willing accomplices of apartheid, a complicity; that endured to the very end of
the regime’s existence. (The fact that the likes of Lady Margaret Thatcher now elbow their way to the head
of queues to s hake Mandela’s hand must not allow us to forget that, if left to them, Mandela would still be
on Robben Island.) These points cannot be developed here but are thoroughly documented in an extensive
literature.
Cheap and highly regimented labor, the bedrock upon which the South African economy was built, created
enormous wealth for some citizens of western countries, and, through cheap raw materials and agricultural
products, benefited most West inhabitants to a greater or lesser extent. This needs to be clearly understood.
For it must equally be accepted that “ordinary” citizens might well have a small financial cost to bear if the
debt is canceled.
The cost to be borne by banks and citizens alike, by canceling the apartelitist debt, would be the West’s
contribution towards an Affirmative Action program directed at the majority of South Africans rather than
its highly elitist current form. Cancellation of the apartheid debt would be the West’s reparation for its
complicity with apartheid. The cost would be the West’s acknowledgment of the debt it owes countless
millions of black South Africans over many, many generations. This acknowledgment would in effect be the
West’s submission before the Truth & Reconciliation Commission.
Western Precedents for Debt Cancellation
Western Governments and banks have already shown a willingness to be governed by non-commercial
considerations and, indeed, to take the initiative in canceling (some of) the debt owed them. Poland and
Egypt have both recently benefited from western generosity. Both countries were granted substantial debt
relief for exclusively political reasons. Neither country qualified under the compelling doctrines of Odious
Debt yet each was awarded genuine relief.
77
Repudiating the Debt
The question that needs to be asked is: What happens if, despite everything, the negotiations fail. What
happens if the banks and/or their governments refuse to cancel the debt.
Unilateral Cancellation
In actual practice, long before the collapse of the negotiations South African n egotiators would know how
far the bankers were prepared to go — or to be pushed. The South African negotiators should be prepared,
if necessary, to indicate South Africa’s readiness to cancel the debt unilaterally should they be forced into
that position. The precedent for such unilateral action — let us remind ourselves — was established in 1898
by the US when, acting in accord with the Doctrine of Odious Debt, it unilaterally repudiated Cuba’s
Spanish debt.
Mobilizing Civil Society
It remains an open question whether, or to what extent, the South African government would be
enthusiastic even to enter into the negotiations to cancel the debt by agreement. Mandela has in the not too
distant past been exceedingly quick to repudiate the ANC’s secretary -general and other official
pg_0020
spokespeople when they warned that an ANC government would consider whether to honor debts incurred
by the outgoing apartheid government.
78
What can be predicted with greater assuredness is that the government would almost certainly need
encouragement in order to be willing to take unilateral action. All the people who are currently suffering the
Government’s economic policies (this point is developed below) and all the people who would stand to
benefit from an RDP that was not permanently suspended in a state of (virtual) postponement due to
insufficient resources being made available — there of course being a great deal of overlap between the two
groups — would form a natural constituency for a mass based campaign of direct-action democracy. It
would be hard for a popularly elected government that sees itself as the custodian of the people’s
aspirations to ignore the people’s demonstrated will.
In the same way that demonstrating the West’s complicity in apartheid is necessary if one is to promote and
sustain international solidarity, so an understanding of the Government’s economic policies and the options
available for South Africa would be a condition for the popular mobilization at home.
There Are Always Alternatives
What can be guaranteed is that business interests and the Government’s present economic advisors would
speak with one voice on this issue. And they would do so loudly and at the earliest indication that the
government might be contemplating, not unilateral action, but even just negotiations to cancel the debt with
the consent of the creditors. With most of the media as their accomplices, they could be expected to assert
that there is no alternative to GEAR — “Growth, Employment & Redistribution” — the Government’s macro -
economic policy document. They would proclaim the end of civilization if we upset international bankers
and financial speculators; they will predict the collapse of the economy, unemployment and starvation on a
scale that dwarfs even today’s horrendous levels. A balance of payments crisis would be affirmed as a
certainty. Above all, they will assert the collapse of economic activity in the absence of the lifeline of
international capital.
There dire warning can be predicted with such confidence because they derive from the standard economic
theories that have prevailed for a long time in South Africa. What is not recognized — but needs to be
widely publicized according to the strategy being unfolded here — is that the assumptions behind each and
every warning have been questioned by respected economists who are guided by the same broad economic
principles as the harbingers of doom. A perusal of the business press shows that mainstream economists
hardly speak with a single voice. Not being privy to these controversies, the general pubic would hardly
believe the range of alternatives being presented.
The point is that power helps decide what is “The Truth” in many aspects of life; and it serves the interests
of those presently powerful in South Africa to popularize the idea that “There is no alternative” to reliance
on the good-will of foreign banks.
Stuck in GEAR
Any debate about alternatives invariably carries a degree of uncertainty. This uncertainty is almost a matter
of definition in cases where radical alternatives are being considered. Being radical almost certainly means
that the alternatives are more or less untested. Uncertainty is a necessary feature of the untested.
However, the debate on alternative economic policies, that do not make us all hostages to foreign capital,
can firmly be anchored to three certainties.
These who would be apocalyptic in their warnings of the consequences for democratic South Africa if the
government, on grounds of morality and justice, were unilaterally to repudiate the foreign debt, forget one
over-riding fact. It is just over ten years since the government of odious apartheid unilaterally froze (part of)
its foreign debt. As a consequence, South Africa did experience capital-starvation in South Africa,
79
and
the economy did indeed suffer.
80
As always workers and the huge segment of the marginalized suffered
most. But the economy did survive. This is the first certainty anchoring the debate on alternatives.
pg_0021
If survival was demonstrably possible in the worst of possible contexts, both at home and abroad where the
debt-freeze further fueled the world -wide campaign to free South Africa, why should the same not happen
when the circumstances are considerably better. Why should survival not be even more likely when the
action of a now democratic government would be fully supported by the majority of its citizens and when, it
can safely be assumed, the majority of world opinion would be against the banks and those governments
that refused to acknowledge their own huge debt to the majority o f South Africans.
The second certainty concerns the IMF/World Bank. Since 1991 South Africa’s economic policies have
increasingly been shaped by both these institutions. GEAR, the government’s macro -economic policy
document of June 1996, was heavily influenced by direct World Bank input. Two World Bank economists
helped formulate GEAR, which, moreover, was based on an economic model provided by the World Bank.
As early as 1992, a Business Day journalist noted approvingly that the World Bank was a “key player in the
formulation of post-apartheid economic policy” not because of any loans provided but “by making
available…its vast experience.”
81
The “vast experience” of World Bank/IMF policy is one of manifest failure not only for the great majority of
the people who have had to suffer their policies but, frequently, even in terms of the World Bank/IMF’s own
very narrow economic criteria for what they consider to be growth. The failure of World Bank/IMF
economics — especially in Africa — has been extensively documented by numerous writers over the years.
It is a subject that cannot be undertaken here. But the fact of the failure provides the strategy that is being
outlined here with its secondary certainty.
The third certainty is the glaring failure of the Government’s existing macro -economic policies to deliver the
socio -economic benefits to which the government says it is committed. Foreign capital is absolutely critical
to the realization of those benefits, according to current policy. Ever since 1991 the ANC and now the
government have been doing and saying whatever they were told would please foreign capitalists. That this
often meant turning formal ANC policy on its head has been no obstacle. Even the business press has been
ready to acknowledge the Government’s “huge emphasis on being investor friendly.”
82
There appears to be no bottom line when it comes to placating the foreign investor. Out went nationalization
to be replaced by constitutional safeguards to private property that far exceed those of most other
countries. Radical land reform was ditched because it was inconsistent with the sanctity of private property
and “sent out the wrong signals” to foreign capitalists. The first Finance Minister and Governor of the
Reserve Bank of democratic South African were also the last Finance Minister and Governor of the Reserve
Bank of apartheid South Africa — a choice urged upon Mandela by Michael Camdessus, Managing
Director of the IMF, and other business circles in order to “reassure international investors,” as the highly
influential Financial Times of London editorialized.
83
For the same reason, Mandela appointed a retired leading banker, Liebenberg, to replace Derek Keys, the
first Finance Minister when Keys unexpectedly resigned. Within days of the announcement of his
appointment, Liebenberg made his position perfectly plain. His role was to steer South Africa back into the
world economy “by achieving what the international market and agencies see as reasonable and fair.”
84
To
make South Africa even more enticing for foreign profit -making, the government was advised to provide tax
incentives for foreign capital. It duly obliged. business demanded the abolition of the financial rand. The
ANC quickly agreed, followed 3 months later by the Governor of the Reserve Bank who announced, in June
1993, that the financial rand would go “within four years.” The IMF loan of December 1993 approved
retaining the financial rand for 3-5 years.
85
It was actually abolished just over a year later, in March 1995.
Always doing more than required according to a neo-liberal policy agenda has become a pattern in the
Government’s economic practice. World Bank economist, Michael Walton, speaking of the South African
situation, described inflation of 20% as “moderate” and said South Africa could comfortably live with it.
86
The government has gone instead for single-figure inflation.
The conditions attached to the IMF loan of 1993 include the requirement to reduce the Government’s
budget deficit to 6% of GDP. However, the IMF accepted that the deficit might exceed that figure for the first
pg_0022
few years. The IMF merely urged that the ratio should be reduced in the direction of 6%. The World Bank,
also in a 1993 document, was even more accommodating. It approved a deficit of 10% for the rest of the
decade.
87
In its eagerness to appease capital, GEAR sets a target deficit of just 3% by 1999. The new
government surprised many by its readiness to open the domestic market to (unequal) foreign competition,
as required by GATT (now the World Trade Organization — WTO) in 1994. The Government’s actual
practice has been to remove import tariffs at a rate even faster than required by the WTO.
But nothing the government has done has been enough. Foreign capital has far richer pastures in which to
forage in other parts of the world. South Africa’s net, long-term capital inflow has been very small and
sporadic and has occurred only since late 1994. Moreover, very little of the capital that has come in has
gone into long-term, direct investments that provide new productiv e capacities. Indeed, the primary function
of capital inflows has increasingly been to pay for capital outflows, as the Financial Mail acknowledged.
88
At first, in the early 1990s, when the expected flood of foreign capital turned into a drought, the “experts”
who predicted the bountiful harvest fertilized by foreign capital, attributed the problem to fears of socialism
and nationalization. So the ANC stopped talking about such things. But foreign capital still stayed at home.
In came a new explanation. This time “political uncertainty” over the peaceful transition to democracy was
the answer. The Reserve Bank Governor predicted an early return of the capital that left South Africa in a
torrent, in the run-up to the 1994 election. The Governor spoke of a “substantial backflow” of capital that
would “dramatically” change the situation.
89
The Sunday Times described the outflow as having reached
“mega-proportions.”
90
Indeed, the hardly insignificant R3.7bn that left the country in 1992 increased 440%
in 1993, when it totaled R16.3bn.
91
And that is just the capital the fled legally. The miracle of the peaceful
birth of the “rainbow” nation made no difference, however. “Political violence” between the ANC and
Inkatha was shipped into the explanatory frame. But bringing the violence under control made no difference
either. Foreign capital remained as elusive as ever.
The problem was then identified as the financial rand. So out went the fin rand; but the drought persisted
unabated. And so it has continued with ever more explanations being added to account for the flood that
refuses to flow. The country’s ability to survive the local elections was a favorite throughout 1995. Crime,
the delay in implementing privatization, the persistence of labor regulations that restrict the freedom of
capital and the failure to abolish exchange controls are amongst the current favorites. (The government is
told it will have to borrow R17bn in order to pay for the R50bn that is excepted to flood out of the country
when exchange controls are lifted. Yet, the logic behind abolishing exchange controls is supposedly to bring
capital in to South Africa!) Uncertainty over the 1999 general election and the successor to Mandela as
President are amongst the more fanciful of the recent diagnoses.
The failure of existing foreign-investor-friendly policies is even more overwhelming that the above facts
indicate. From the late 1980s to the early 1990s the air was full with optimism regarding the prospects for the
post-apartheid economy. Much of this optimism was well-grounded in an economy that would be free of the
apartheid distortions, inefficiencies, duplications and waste.
92
The optimism also derived from the freeing of
human creativity and the access to talent that would be available with the death of apartheid. Finally, the
optimism was bedded I the post-apartheid readmittance of South Africa into a world that, moreover, would
be full of good will towards the new nation. These are all real considerations. The failure of the country’s
economic policies is even more stark when contextualized in this not to be repeated set of circumstances.
(What must be noted in passing is that there are some people who have every reason to view the present
economic order as being highly successful. But even the Financial Mail had no difficulty in seeing how very
limited this success actually is. The headline to a recent leading article spoke volumes when it declared:
“Shift to Right Benefits Black Elite.”
93
)
pg_0023
Alternatives to Foreign Capital
Elaboration of this huge subject is beyond the scope of this report. Suffice it to say that South Africa has —
and indeed suffers from — a huge stock of unproductive capital
94
and that documents detailing alternatives
to foreign capital do exist. Most of these documents need to be dusted down; for they come from an earlier
age. However, even the present version of the RDP contains alternatives that have quietly been ignored.
The original versions of the RDP contain much more daring alternatives. So, too, do now mostly forgotten
COSATU documents. Policy options that have already been identified include: prescribed assets; a wealth
tax
95
(with variations that include heavy death duties, a general tax on luxury imports, a swimming-pool tax
and a tax on ownership of more than one home); delaying approval of capital flight by the major insurance
companies; applying additional exchange controls and making it harder to transfer funds illegally; tight
control on the importation of capital-intensive equipment as part of an industrial strategy to use home -
manufactured appropriate technology that, being more labor intensive, moreover helps transform large-scale
unemployment from a problem into an advantage; reducing the pace of trade liberalization to World Trade
Organization requirements and thereby dampening the local demand for imports; tightly regulating the
availability of luxury -related credit; guiding finance, at favorable rates, to where it is socially needed;
96
cross-subsides to help make electricity, water and sewage affordable for all. Freedom from the imposed
dictates of the market also makes room for alternate forms of economic ownership and organization that are
people -centered and far less reliant on foreign capital for their viability.
The point of all this is that a whole range of alternatives have already been theorized. We also have the
talent amongst ourselves to devise our own solutions to our own problems. What is currently lacking is the
spirit to be daring — and, of the course, the determining political will.
Debtors’ Cartel or Individual Action
The ideal of all countries caught in the debt trap forming a cartel to maximize the effectiveness of an
international campaign of debt repudiation has been around for some time. That nothing has ever come of it
indicates the difficulties in implementing and idea of such obvious appeal.
Campaigns involving Odious Debt, on the other hand, do not lend themselves well to collective action. The
differences in the details of each country’s circumstances are too broad for a joint case. Moreover, morality
has been so severely mauled by the moloch of commercialism, in the decades since an Odious Debt claim
was last made, that only a case of pristine virtue stands any chance of renewing the Doctrine.
For these several reasons, the collective cause would probably be best served by the individual action most
likely to succeed in setting a modern -day precedent for the Doctrine. A strong argument can be made that
the most effective form of solidarity open to the new South Africa on behalf of the hundreds of mi llions of
people caught in the debt trap around the world, would be success in obtaining the creditors’ consent to
cancel the odious apartheid debt.
No Time to Lose
This strategy comes with one acknowledged and major defect. Time. Major debt repayments are due this
year. The time to act is now.
April 1997.
References
Adams, Patricia (1991) Odious Debts: Loose Lending, Corruption, And the Third World’s Environmental
Legacy. London: Probe International.
Barber, Simon (1992a) “ANC to Outline plans in US,” in Business Day 8 October.
Barber, Simon (1992b) “World Bank works discreetly to shape SA economic policy,” in Business Day 13
October.
pg_0024
Bond, Patrick (1991) Commanding Heights & Community Control — New Economics for a New South Africa.
Johannesburg: Raven Press.
Bond, Patrick (1992) “Community Development Finance for Electrification,” in Theron, Paul (ed.) (1992)
Proceedings of the ANC National Meeting on Electrification — University of Cape Town February
1992. African National Congress and Centre for Development Studies, University of the Western Cape.
Bond, Patrick (1996) “Alternatives to Government Austerity Measures,” AIDC Newsletter (forthcoming).
Bond, Patrick (1997) Elite Transition — Uneven Development, Neo-Liberalism & Globalisation in South
Africa. London: Pluto Press (forthcoming).
Botha, CJ (1990) “Discussions & Resolution on South Africa in the United Nations — 1989,” in South
African Yearbook of International Law, Vol. 15, 1989-90. Pretoria: University of South Africa.
Bradlow, Daniel D. (1991) “Debt, Development, and Human Rights: Lessons from South Africa,” in Michigan
Journal of International Law, 12, 647 -Summer.
Crawford -Browne, Terry (1997), Personal interview, Cape Town, January 1997.
Davie, Kevin (1994) “We still have chains to lose,” Sunday Times, 6 November.
Fergusson-Brown, Kevin (198.) “The Legality of Economic Sanctions against South Africa in Contemporary
International Law,” in South African Yearbook of International Law, Vol. 14, 1988-89. Pretoria:
University of South Africa.
Finance Week (1995a) “Foreign debt: We still owe plenty,” 30 March.
Finance Week (1995b) “Reliance on short -term money,” 3 August.
Foreign Trade Research Institute (1994) Doing Business in Poland. Warsaw: Polish Ministry of Foreign
Economic Relations.
Frankenberg, Gunter & Knieper, Rolf (1984) “Legal Problems of the Overindebtedness of Developing
Countries: the Current Relevance of the Doctrine of Odious Debts,” in International Journal of the
Sociology of Law, 1984, 12.
Garner, Jonathan & Leape, Jonathan (1991) South Africa’s Borrowings on International Capital Markets:
Recent Developments in Historical Perspective. London School of Economics, Centre for the Study of
the South African Economy & International Finance, Research Paper No. 5.
Gidlow, RM (1989) “Debt Reduction versus growth oriented balance: the case of South Africa,” in The
South African Banker, 87, 1 (February).
Goldin, Ian (1992) External Financial Assistance & Post-Apartheid South Africa. University of the Western
Cape, Economic Policy Series No. 9.
Ha rris, Lawrence (1987) “South Africa’s External Debt Crisis,” in Onimode, Bade (ed.) (1989) The IMF, the
World Bank and the African Debt — Vol. 1: The Economic Impact. London: Institute for African
Alternatives & Zed Books Ltd.
Hirsch, Alan (1989b) “The Origins & Implications of South Africa’s Continuing Financial Crisis,” in
Transformation, 9.
Institute for African Alternatives (nd) The IMF, World Bank & Africa — Report of a Conference on “The
Impact of the IMF & World Bank Policies on the People of African.” London: IFAA.
Leap, Jonathan (1992) “South Africa Foreign Debt: Implications of the debt crisis of 1985 and prospects for
the 1990s,” in Centre for Development Research (1992) Beyond Apartheid — Discussion Papers on a
Democratic Development in South Africa: Proceedings of a Conference on Post-Apartheid South
Africa, Copenhagen, February 1991. Copenhagen: CDR.
Leap, Jonathan I (1991) South Africa Foreign Debt and the Standstill, 1985-1990. Centre for the Study of the
South African Economy and International Finance, London School of Economics. Research Paper No. 1.
Mabirizi, D. (1989) “Impact of IMF-World Bank on Lesotho,” in Onimode, Bade (ed.) (1989) The IMF, the
World Bank and the African Debt — Vol. I: The Economic Impact. London: Institute for African
Alternatives & Zed Books Ltd.
Mesjasz, Czeslaw (1995) “Politics and Reorganization of Commercial Debt: Negotiations between Poland and
the London Club (1981-1994).” Paper present to the PIN/IIASA book project seminar: “International
Economic Negotiations: Theory versus Reality,” IIASA, Laxenburg, Austria, 3-4 March. (Draft version.)
Millward, Charles & Pillay, Vella (1966) “Rand at Risk,” in Finance Week, 11 April.
Moye, Melissa (1997) Mobilizing Resources for National Desertification Funds through Debt-for-
Environment Swaps. New York: United Nationals Development Programme Office to Combat
Desertification and Drought.
pg_0025
Onimode, Bade (ed.) (1989) The IMF, the World Bank and the African Debt — Vol. 1 The Economic Impact.
London: Institute for African Alternatives & Zed Books Ltd.
Padayachee, Vishnu (1992) “The IMF & World Bank in post-apartheid South Africa: Prospects & Dangers,”
in Centre for Development Research (1992) Beyond Apartheid — Discussion Papers on a Democratic
Development in South Africa: Proceedings of a Conference on Post-Apartheid South Africa,
Copenhagen, February 1991. Copenhagen: CDR.
Padayachee, Vishnu (1994) “Debt, Development & Democracy: the IMF in Post-Apartheid South Africa,” in
Review of African Political Economy, No. 62.
South African Reserve Bank Quarterly Bulletin, December 1996.
Savage, Michael (1986) The Cost of Apartheid — Inaugural Lecture. Cape Town: University of Cape Town,
New Series pamphlet No. 121.
Theron, Paul (ed.) (1992) Proceedings of the ANC National Meeting on Electrification — University of Cape
Town February 1992. African National Congress and Centre for Development Studies, University of the
Western Cape.
United States General Accounting Office (1990) South Africa — Debt Rescheduling & Potential for Financial
Sactions: Briefing Report to Congressional Requesters.
Wood, Sharon (1995) “Deficit Looms,” in Finance Week, 16 February.
Wright, Eric Olin (1985) Classes. London: Verso.
Young, Gordon (1992) The Price for Apartheid: The wealth tax and how it can pay for the re-construction of
black communities. Economic Policy Paper No. 3. Cape Town: Labour Research Service.
1
The aphorism comes from the Paris Uprising of 1968.
2
By suggesting a Susan George type solution of converting debt to a local development fund, the ANC’s
Banking/Finance handbook is a partial exception.
3
I refer to Marx of the Groucho variety.
4
Wright (1985: 1)
5
What is most often ignored is that the 3.6% does not include parastal and private debt that the government
has responsibility for paying.
6
Finance Week (1995b; Millward & Pillay (1996); South African Reserve Bank (1996:: S95)
7
I have drawn heavily on Adams (1991: 162-70) in what follows.
8
This and the preceding quotations come from Adams (1991: 163-4).
9
Cited by Adams (1991: 166).
10
Cited by Adams (1991: 165).
11
Cited by Adams (1991: 170).
12
Cited by Adams (1991: 167-8). Such was the international significance of Great Britain vs. Costa Rica that
Chief Just Taft accepted no payment for adjudicating the case. He explained [Cited by Adams (1991: 168)].
So far as the payment of the expenses of the arbitration is concerned, I know of none for me to fix.
Personally, it gives me pleasure to contribute my service in the consideration, discussion and decision of
the questions presented. I am glad to have the opportunity of manifesting my intense interest in the
promotion of the judicial settlement of international disputes, and accept as full reward for any service I may
have rendered, the honor of being chosen to decide these important issues between the high contracting
parties.
13
Cited by Adams (1991: 169).
14
Ibid.
15
Adams (1991: 169-70).
16
Paragraph 1 of the Principle of Equal Rights and Self Determination of People, in GA Resolution 2625.
17
Article 3.
18
Articles 55 and 56.
19
Advisory Opinion of the ICJ, The Legal Consequences for States of the Continued Presence of South
Africa in Namibia (South West Africa) notwithstanding Security Council Resolution 276 (1970), 1971 ICJ
Reports 31.
See Fergusson-Brown (198.: 63-64) for some of the other fundamental human rights violated by apartheid.
20
Cited by Fergusson-Brown (198.: 64).
pg_0026
21
Military & Paramilitary Activities in and against Nicaragua 1986 ICJ Reports 230. Cited by Fergusson-
Brown (198.: 64).
22
See Fergusson-Brown (198.: 64-5) for examples and references.
23
See Fergusson-Brown (198.: 66 for examples and references.
24
Fergusson-Brown (198.: 66).
25
Padayachee (1992: 268).
26
Ibid.
27
For Tanzania see, for example, Seidman (1986: 252). For Zambia see, for instance, Fundanga (1987: 18)
Padayachee (1992: 273) Seidman (1986: 252).
28
Padayachee (1991: 89-90).
29
Padayachee (1992: 265-66).
30
Both Padayachee (1992: 265).
31
Padayachee (1992: 266).
32
Padayachee (1992: 267).
33
Ibid.
34
Goldin (1992: 23).
35
Mabirizi (1989: 163).
36
Ibid.
37
The Star 28.7.1985.
38
This summary borrows heavily from Hirsch (1989: 39-40).
39
Harris (1987: 178).
40
See Hirsch (1989: 40-1).
41
(London) Financial Times 27.11.1985.
42
6.2.1986.
43
All Harris (1987: 189).
44
Both, The Guardian, 21.2.1986.
45
Finance Week , 26.3.1987.
46
See, for instance, Bradlow (1991: 663-4).
47
Cape Argus, 19.7.1989.
48
Cape Argus, 8.8.1989.
49
All Cape Times, 7.9.1989.
50
Cape Times, 4.10.1989.
51
Cape Times, 17.10.1989.
52
Quoted by Botha (1990: 200). The resolution, passed a month after the third arrangement had been
finalize d, could do no more than “urge” compliance because it was opposed by the Governments of Great
Britain and the US.
53
See, for instance, Leap (1991: 13) & United States General Accounting Office (1990: 6-7).
54
See, for instance, Leap (1991: 13) & United States General Accounting Office (1990: 7); Cape Times,
17.10.1989.
55
See, for instance, Cape Argus, 8.8.1989.
56
Cape Times, 20.10.1989.
57
United States General Accounting Office (1990:2). The Fourth and Final Arrangement runs from 1.1.1994 to
15.8.2001 at the end of which time the frozen debt is due to be completely amortized.
58
Leap (1991: 3) The bulk of the debt that was frozen in 1985 was short -term, inter-bank loans.
59
Hirsch (1989: 39).
60
Goldin (1992: 17).
61
7.9.1985.
62
Lawrence (1987: 183) Short-term losses were so important (and lucrative) that South African banks opened
offices abroad. Nedbank, the most energetic in this area, had offices in London, New York, Zurich, the
Caman Islands and Jersey, in 1988 [Hirsch (1989: 49)].
63
This and all the other in formation on CHIPS & SWIFT comes from United States General Accounting
Office (1990: 8-10).
pg_0027
64
Trade Credits are pre-payments to suppliers for the cost of commodities exported to third parties. Most of
the credits are interbank transactions and a large number of them are guaranteed by the Government’s of the
exporting countries. Unless otherwise stated all information dealing with trade credits for South Africa
comes from Hirsch (1989: 46-7).
65
Finance Week , 27.4.1989.
66
Euromoney, March 1987 — cited by Hirs ch (1989: 46).
67
Hirsch (1989: 43-44).
68
See Cape Times, “Swiss stave off SA debt squeeze” 19.7.1989; Garner & Leape (1991: iv -v); Goldin (1992:
18); Leape (1992: 243-4).
69
Preece (1987: 626).
70
For the costs of apartheid, see, for instance, Savage (1986).
71
ESKOM is responsible for the largest single slice of the total apartheid debt. For an analysis of ESKOM’s
financing see Bond (1992: 158-63).
72
Crawford -Browne (1997a). Terry Crawford -Browne is an ex-banker who acted as advisor to Desmond Tutu
and the other clerics during their campaign to end foreign bank loans to the apartheid state.
73
Cape Times, 24.2.1997.
74
The Paris Club would be an obvious body with which to initiate the negotiations.
75
Saying this is not to lose sight of the “hard-headdress” with which creditor Government’s and bankers
have approached the whole question of the debt burden of the so-called “Third -World.” The arrangements
they have made even in respect of the 41 countries they have identified as being “heavily -indebted poor
countries” and which they accept have no way of repaying their individual debts in the normal manner have
been less than generous.
76
Leape (1992: 233). The Swiss figure understates the true position as it excludes gold loans (ibid.).
77
For Poland see Foreign Trade Research Institute (1994) & Mesjasz (1995). For Egypt see Moye (1997: 22).
78
See, for instance, Cape Argus, 2.10.1991, 3.10.1991, 22.1.1992, 8.2.1992, 19.2.1992, 5.9.1992; and Cape
Times, 12.10.1991, 22.1.1992.
79
Recall that trade credits, interbank loans and private high-risk speculation continued to provide (some)
capital.
80
See, for instance, Gidlow (1989: 25). The difficulties encountered need to be contextualized in the
economics and policy options of apartheid, of course.
81
Barber (1992a). Also see Barber (1992b).
82
Wood (1995).
83
Cited by Cape Argus, 5.5.1994.
84
Quoted by Cape Argus, 12.7.1994.
85
Davie (1994d).
86
Cape Times, 11.9.1992.
87
Padayachee (1194: 591).
88
Financial Mail (1993b).
89
Sunday Times, 20.2.1994.
90
Ibid.
91
Ibid.
92
See, for instance, Savage (1986).
93
30.8.1996.
94
See, for instance, Bond (1991: Chapter 2 — A Crisis of Over-Accumulation) & Bond (1997).
95
Young (1992).
96
For this and other preceding points, see Bond (1996).